September 21, 2020, Christopher D. Carroll RamseyCassKoopmans
Ramsey (1928), followed much later by Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965), formulated the canonical model of optimal growth for an economy with exogenous ‘labor-augmenting’ technological progress.
The economy has a perfectly competitive production sector that uses a Cobb-Douglas aggregate production function
| (1) |
to produce output using capital and labor.1 Labor hours (the same as population) increases exogenously at a constant rate2
| (2) |
and is an index of labor productivity that grows at rate
| (3) |
Thus, technological progress allows each worker to produce
perpetually more as time goes by with the same amount of physical
capital.3
The quantity is known as the number of ‘efficiency units’ of labor in the
economy.
Aggregate capital accumulates according to
| (4) |
Lower case variables are the upper case version divided by efficiency units, i.e.
| (5) |
Note that
| (6) |
which means that (4) can be divided by and becomes
| (7) |
A steady-state will be a point where .
Equation (7) yields a first candidate for an optimal steady-state of the growth
model: It seems reasonable to argue that the best possible steady-state is the one
that maximizes . This is the “golden rule” optimality condition of
Phelps (1961), an article well worth reading; this is one of the chief contributions
for which Phelps won the Nobel prize.
Now suppose that there is a social planner whose goal is to maximize the discounted sum of CRRA utility from per-capita consumption:
| (8) |
But . Recall that for a variable growing at rate
,
| (9) |
so if the economy started off in period 0 with productivity , by date
we
can rewrite
| (10) |
Using (10) and the other results above, we can rewrite the social planner’s objective function as
| (11) |
Thus, defining and normalizing the initial level of
productivity to
, the complete optimization problem can be formulated
as
| (12) |
subject to
| (13) |
which has a discounted Hamiltonian representation
| (14) |
The first discounted Hamiltonian optimization condition requires :
| (15) |
The second discounted Hamiltonian optimization condition requires:
| (16) |
where the definition of is motivated by thinking of
as the
interest rate net of depreciation and dilution.
This is called the “modified golden rule” (or sometimes the “Keynes-Ramsey rule” because it was originally derived by Ramsey with an explanation attributed to Keynes).
Thus, we end up with an Euler equation for consumption growth that is just
like the Euler equation in the perfect foresight partial equilibrium consumption
model, except that now the relevant interest rate can vary over time as
varies.
Substituting in the modified time preference rate gives
| (17) |
and finally note that defining per capita consumption so that
,
| (18) |
and since (17) can be written
| (19) |
we have
| (20) |
so the formula for per capita consumption growth (as a function of ) is
identical to the model with no growth (equation (17) with
).
Any important differences between the no-growth model and the model
with growth therefore must come through the channel of differences in
.
The assumption of labor augmenting technological progress was made because it
implies that in steady-state, per-capita consumption, income, and capital all grow at
rate .4
implies that at the steady-state value of
,
| (21) |
Thus, the steady-state will be higher if capital is more productive (
is
higher), and will be lower if consumers are more impatient, population growth is
faster, depreciation is greater, or technological progress occurs more
rapidly.
While the RCK model has an analytical solution for its steady-state, it does not
have an analytical solution for the transition to the steady-state. The usual
method for analyzing models of this kind is a phase diagram in and
. The
first step in constructing the phase diagram is to take the differential equations
that describe the system and find the points where they are zero. Thus, from (7)
we have that
implies
| (22) |
and we have already solved for the (constant) that characterizes the
locus. These can be combined to generate the borders between the phases in the
phase diagram, as illustrated in figure 1.
Actually, as stated so far, the solution to the problem is very simple: The
consumer should spend an infinite amount in every period. This solution is not
ruled out by anything we have yet assumed (except possibly the fact that once
becomes negative the production function is undefined).
Obviously, this is not the solution we are looking for. What is missing is that we have not imposed anything corresponding to the intertemporal budget constraint. In this context, the IBC takes the form of a “transversality condition,”
| (23) |
The intuitive purpose of this unintuitive equation is basically to prevent the capital stock from becoming negative or infinity as time goes by. Obviously a capital stock that was negative for the entire future could not satisfy the equation. And a capital stock that is too large will have an arbitrarily small interest rate, which will result in the LHS of the TVC being a positive number, again failing to satisfy the TVC.
Figure 2 shows three paths for and
that satisfy (17) and (7). The
topmost path, however, is clearly on a trajectory toward zero then negative
,
while the bottommost path is heading toward an infinite
. Only the middle
path, labelled the “saddle path,” satisfies both (17) and (7) as well as the TVC
(23).
An explicit numerical solution to the Ramsey problem, with a description of a solution method and its mathematical/computational underpinnings, is available here.
Cass, David (1965): “Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation,” Review of Economic Studies, 32, 233–240.
Grossman, Gene M., Elhanan Helpman, Ezra Oberfield, and Thomas Sampson (2016): “Balanced Growth Despite Uzawa,” Working Paper 21861, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Koopmans, Tjalling C. (1965): “On the concept of optimal economic growth,” in (Study Week on the) Econometric Approach to Development Planning, chap. 4, pp. 225–87. North-Holland Publishing Co., Amsterdam.
Phelps, Edmund S. (1961): “The Golden Rule of Accumulation,” American Economic Review, pp. 638–642, Available at http://teaching.ust.hk/~econ343/PAPERS/EdmundPhelps-TheGoldenRuleofAccumulation-AfableforGrowthMen.pdf.
Ramsey, Frank (1928): “A Mathematical Theory of Saving,” Economic Journal, 38(152), 543–559.