February 7, 2021, Christopher D. Carroll Envelope
This handout shows how the Envelope theorem is used to derive the consumption Euler equation in a multiperiod optimization problem with geometric discounting and intertemporally separable utility.
The consumer’s goal from the perspective of date is to
| (1) |
subject to the dynamic budget constraint
| (2) |
The problem can be written in Bellman equation form as
| (3) |
The first order condition for (3) can be written as
| (4) |
and we can define a function that returns the
that solves the max
problem for any given
. That is, for
the first order condition (4)
will hold so that
| (5) |
Now define a function
| (6) |
with partial derivatives
| (7) |
| (8) |
and note that by definition
| (9) |
The Chain Rule of differentiation tells us that
|
Here’s the key insight: The assumption that consumers are optimizing
means that we will always be evaluating the value function and its
derivatives at a that satisfies the first-order optimality condition
(5).1
Thus we have from (7) that
| (10) |
This means that the second term in (10) is always equal to zero, so from (8) we obtain
| (11) |
Now notice that the RHS’s of (4) and (11) are identical, so we can equate the left hand sides,
| (12) |
and since a corresponding equation will hold in period we can rewrite (11)
as
| (13) |
The general principle can be condensed into a rule of thumb by realizing that
the Envelope theorem will always imply that the total derivative of a value
function with respect to any choice variable must be equal to zero for optimizing
consumers (because the first order condition holds). Thus we could have
obtained the result immediately by treating as though it were a constant
(that is, treating the problem as though
) and taking the derivative
of Bellman’s equation with respect to
directly. This leads immediately to
the key result:
| (14) |