September 21, 2020, Christopher D. Carroll RBC-Prescott
This handout presents the elements of the original Real Business Cycle model of aggregate fluctuations, as laid out by Prescott (1986), along with a few critiques articulated by Summers (1986) and others.
Consider a representative household whose goal is to maximize
| (1) |
where is the fraction of time the representative agent spends at leisure (not
working); the alternative to leisure is the number of hours you work, which
will be designated
, and the time endowment is normalized to 1, so
that
| (2) |
Assume that the structure of the utility function is
| (3) |
Think about the maximum amount of income that could be gained if the representative agent worked every waking hour:
| (4) |
The representative agent can then think of deciding to ‘purchase’ two things
with this endowment of income: leisure whose price is
, or consumption,
whose price is normalized to one.
Over the past century in the U.S., wages have risen very substantially, but hours worked have not declined much if at all. (Ramey and Francis (2006)). What kind of utility function implies that the budget share of a good (leisure) remains constant even as the price of the good changes sharply? A Cobb-Douglas utility function. Hence the assumption that utility is obtained from a Cobb-Douglas aggregate of consumption and leisure is consistent with the lack of a strong trend in hours worked per worker.
Since workers are choosing how many hours to work as well how much to
consume, a first order condition will characterize the optimal choice
between consumption and leisure within a period. In particular, the price of
leisure is and the price of consumption is 1, so the ratio of the
marginal utility of leisure to the marginal utility of consumption should
be
| (5) |
To see this, note that the consumer’s goal is to
| (6) |
Suppose the consumer has decided to spend a given amount in period
on a combination of consumption and leisure,
| (7) |
Then (6) becomes
| (8) |
for which the FOC is
| (9) |
Returning to (5)
| (10) |
or
| (11) |
Since we know that has been roughly constant over long periods of time,
this implies that as wages rise, consumption rises by roughly the same
amount.
One of the original proimises of the DSGE literature was to calibrate its
business-cycle models based on either long-run facts (like the lack of a trend in
) or on micro data (like intertemporal elasticities estimated using household
data). So how is
calibrated?
If wages are defined as per unit of labor, then if on average consumption
roughly equals labor income we have
| (12) |
So should be calibrated to be equal to the proportion of their available
(i.e. non-sleep) time people spend not working. A 40-hour work week (along
with 8 hours of sleep a day) would yield
. Among other taste
parameters, Prescott chooses log utility (
) and
The aggregate production function is assumed to be Cobb-Douglas,
| (13) |
where where
is the aggregate amount of
Hours available to members of the working population. Constant income shares
and perfect competition imply
| (14) |
so that labor’s share of GDP is roughly constant. Prescott sets labor’s share to a
constant 64 percent, and chooses a depreciation rate of .
The crucial assumption, however, is about the productivity process, since ‘technology shocks’ are assumed to drive business cycles.
Prescott defines the ‘hat’ operator as:
| (15) |
which implies from the production function that
| (16) |
(this is just the Solow residual).
Prescott ‘estimates’ a productivity process that takes the form
| (17) |
with a standard deviation of per quarter.
Prescott makes sufficient assumptions (perfect competition, etc.) so that the social planner’s problem is the same as the decentralized solution. With log utility, the social planner’s problem is
| (18) |
subject to
| (19) |
Prescott argues that the way to judge the model is by whether it produces plausible statistics for standard deviations of the key variables. He produces a table that argues it does:
Since the first column is calibrated, it isn’t a test of the model. The second column comes out of the model, and isn’t too bad a fit. However, the third column is a terrible fit. What it says is that labor input is much more variable over the course of the business cycle than this model would suggest.
What’s going on? To understand the answer, we need to understand why hours fluctuate in this model at all. Recall that we deliberately constructed the model (by choosing a utility function that was Cobb-Douglas in consumption and leisure) in a way designed to prohibit any long-run response of hours worked to wages. Since hours worked are being chosen freely on a day-by-day basis by workers in this model, there must be some incentive that causes them to be willing to put up with short-term variation in hours (over the business cycle).
The answer is that transitory productivity shocks provide an incentive to work harder some times than others. In particular, if there is a temporary positive productivity shock you will be willing to work longer hours than usual, while if there is a negative productivity shock everybody wants to take a vacation.
To see this formally, consider again the first order conditions from the maximization problem. We showed in (11) that
| (20) |
Now note that since (18) is separable in consumption and leisure the intertemporal FOC will imply that
| (21) |
Combining this with (20) gives
| (22) |
What this equation tells us is that there are two ways to make (and
therefore
) fluctuate over the business cycle:
| (23) |
so if the labor supply response is not being driven by wage differences, there should be a one-for-one comovement of consumption with leisure - i.e. recessions should be periods of high consumption and booms should be periods of low consumption!
This latter is a quite general problem with the DSGE framework in which fluctuations in employment over the business cycle are driven by voluntary changes in hours worked.
Prescott, Edward C. (1986): “Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 25, 11–44, http://ideas.repec.org/p/fip/fedmsr/102.html.
Ramey, Valerie A., and Neville Francis (2006): “A Century of Work and Leisure,” NBER Working Paper Number 12264.
Summers, Lawrence H. (1986): “Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle Theory,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 10, 23–27, http://minneapolisfed.org/research/QR/QR1043.pdf.