September 21, 2020, Christopher D. Carroll BrockMirman
Brock and Mirman (1972) provided the first optimizing growth model with unpredictable (stochastic) shocks.
The social planner’s goal is to solve the problem:
| (1) |
|
where is the level of productivity in period
, which is now allowed to be
stochastic (alternative assumptions about the nature of productivity shocks are
explored below). Note the key assumption that the depreciation rate on capital is
100 percent.
In this model the capital stock is not useful as a state variable: Because capital
has a 100 percent depreciation rate, all that matters to the consumer when
choosing how much to consume is how much income they have now, and not
how that income breaks down into a part due to and a part due to
.
The first step is to rewrite the problem in Bellman equation form
| (2) |
and take the first order condition:
|
where our definition of helps clarify the relationship of this equation to
the usual consumption Euler equation (and you should think about why this is
the right definition of the interest factor in this model).
Now we show that this FOC is satisfied by the consumption function
, where
. To see this, note first that the proposed
consumption rule implies that
.
The first order condition says
|
An important way of judging a macroeconomic model and deciding whether it makes sense is to examine the model’s implications for the dynamics of aggregate variables. Defining lower case variables as the log of the corresponding upper case variable, this model says that the dynamics of the capital stock are given by
| (3) |
which tells us that the dynamics of the (log) capital stock have two components:
One component () mirrors whatever happens to the aggregate production
technology; the other is serially correlated with coefficient
equal to capital’s
share in output.
Similarly, since log output is simply , the dynamics of output can
be obtained from
| (4) |
so the dynamics of aggregate output, like aggregate capital, reflect a component
that mirrors and a serially correlated component with serial correlation
coefficient
.
The simplest assumption to make about the level of technology is that its log follows a random walk:
| (5) |
Under this assumption, consider the dynamic effects on the level of
output from a unit positive shock to the log of technology in period
(that is,
where
). Suppose that the
economy had been at its original steady-state level of output
in the
prior period. Then the expected dynamics of output would be given
by
| (6) |
and so on, as depicted in figure 1.
Also interesting is the case where the level of technology follows a white noise process,
| (7) |
The dynamics of income in this case are depicted in figure 2.
The key point of this analysis, again, is that the dynamics of the model are governed by two components: The dynamics of the technology shock, and the assumption about the saving/accumulation process.
For further analysis, consider a nonstochastic version of this model, with
. The consumption Euler equation is
|
But this is an economy with no technological progress, so the steady-state
interest rate must take on the value such that . Thus we must have
or
.
We can further derive the steady state level of capital of a nonstochastic
version of the model in which from (3):
| (8) |
The nonstochastic version of the model is of course not very interesting, except as a point of comparison to the stochastic version of the model. But what could be meant by the ‘steady state’ of a stochastic mdoel that never settles down? We can define a ‘stochastic steady state’ for such models in a number of (potentially) different ways:
We consider here the last of these, which we will show reduces (in this special
case) to the same equation as for the nonstochastic version of the model,
. To see this, rewrite the Euler equation as:
|
where the expectations operator disappears because no variables are stochastic
(the in the numerator and denominator cancel, and
is directly
chosen in
so is known. For any given
, the steady state where
is then where
|
which is the generalization of the nonstochastic solution derived in (8).
The result that the nonstochastic and stochastic steady states are the same is special to the Brock-Mirman model; it is NOT true of many other models of growth; it occurs here because the linearity of the consumption function, among other special assumptions. Furthermore, the third of our possible definitions of a steady state will generally differ at least a little bit from either of the first two.