February 7, 2021, Christopher D. Carroll StickyExpectationsC
Consider a consumer subject to the dynamic budget constraint
| (1) |
where is beginning-of-period bank balances,
is current labor income, and
is the constant interest factor. Actual labor income
is permanent labor income
modified by a transitory shock factor
:
| (2) |
where . Permanent labor income grows by a predictable
factor
from period to period:
| (3) |
so that the expected present discounted value of permanent labor income (‘human wealth’) for an infinite-horizon consumer is
| (4) |
We will assume that the consumer behaves according to the consumption rule
| (5) |
where is the ‘marginal propensity to consume’ out of total wealth
.1
Under these circumstances, RandomWalk shows that consumption will follow a random walk,
| (6) |
Now assume that the economy is populated by a set of measure one of
consumers indexed by a superscript distributed uniformly along the unit
interval. Per capita values of all variables, designated by the upper case, are
the integral over all individuals in the economy, as in Aggregation, so
that
| (7) |
This equation implies that an aggregate version of equation (6) holds,2
| (8) |
In principle, we could allow each individual in this economy to experience a
different transitory and permanent shock from every other individual in each
period. However, for our purposes it is useful to assume that everyone
experiences the same shocks in a given period; that is and
.
Assuming (here and henceforth) that the growth factor for permanent income
is , figure 1 shows the path of consumption (the solid dots) for an
economy populated by omniscient consumers who in periods
for
had experienced
; that is, this economy has had no shocks to
income in the past. (For convenience, the consumer is assumed to have
arrived in period
with
). In period
the consumer draws
and
; thereafter
. The figure shows
. Figure 2 similarly shows the path of
,
again as black dots.
after a shock
, Omniscient Consumers
after a shock
, Omniscient Consumers
Now suppose that not every consumer updates expectations in every period.
Instead, expectations are ‘sticky’: each consumer updates with probability
in each period. Whether the consumer at location
updates in
period
is determined by the realization of the dichotomous random
variable
|
and each period’s updaters are chosen randomly such that a constant proportion
update in each period:
|
It will also be convenient to define the date of consumer ’s most recent
update; we call this object
.
We need a notation to represent sets of consumers defined by the period of
their most recent update. We denote such a set by the condition on ; for
example, the set of consumers whose most recent update, as of date
,
was prior to period
would be
. We denote
the per-capita value of a variable
, among consumers in a set
as
of date
, by
. Dropping the
superscripts to reduce clutter,
per-capita consumption among households who have updated in period
is
therefore
| (9) |
In periods when expectations are not updated, the consumer continues to
spend the same amount as in the most recent period when his expectations were
updated.3 If the
economy is large the proportion of consumers who update their expectations every period
will be .4
Average consumption among those who are not updating in the current period
(for whom
) is then
| (10) |
because consumption per capita among those who are not updating in the
current period is (by assumption) identical to their consumption per capita in
the prior period, which must match aggregate consumption per capita in the
prior period because the set who do not update today is randomly selected from
the population.
Now note that
| (11) |
and
| (12) |
while, defining and
,
|
where (13) follows its predecessor since, among consumers who have updated in
period , the random walk proposition says that
.
Subtracting
from both sides of (13) and substituting the result into (11)
yields
| (13) |
where is a white noise variable (
).
We are finally in position to show how aggregate consumption and wealth would respond in this economy to a transitory positive shock to aggregate labor income like the one considered above for the omniscient model.
Consider the case of a positive shock of size , as before. In the
first period consumption rises only by
, rather than the full amount
corresponding to the permanent income associated with the new level of wealth.
Therefore aggregate wealth in period
will be greater than it would have
been in the omniscient model. Similarly for all subsequent periods. Thus, in
contrast with the omniscient model, the sluggish adjustment of consumption to
the shock means that the shock has a permanent effect on the level of aggregate
wealth, and therefore on the level of aggregate consumption. (Figures 3 and 4
depict the results).
after a shock
; Sticky Expectations in Red/Gray
<
after a shock
; Sticky Expectations in Red/Gray
The sticky expectations model says that consumption growth today can be statistically related to any variable that is related to lagged consumption growth. In particular, if lagged consumption growth is related to lagged income growth (as it certainly will be), then there should be a statistically significant effect of lagged income growth on current consumption growth if expectations are sticky.
If the model derived here could be taken literally, it would suggest estimating an equation of the form
| (14) |
and interpreting the coefficient as a measure of
.
However, if there is potential measurement error in the coefficient
obtained from estimating (14) would be biased toward zero for standard
errors-in-variables reasons (just as regressing consumption on actual income
yields a downward-biased estimate of the response of consumption to permanent
income), which means that the estimate of
would be biased toward 1 (i.e. the
omniscient model in which everyone adjusts all the time). Under these
circumstances, direct estimation of (14) would not be a reliable way to estimate
.
For estimation methods that get around this problem see Sommer (2007),
Carroll, Sommer, and Slacalek (2011), Carroll, Otsuka, and Slacalek (2011).
Those papers consistently find that the proportion of updaters is about
per quarter, so that the serial correlation of ‘true’ consumption
growth is about
per quarter.
Carroll, Christopher D, Misuzu Otsuka, and Jiri Slacalek (2011): “How large are housing and financial wealth effects? A new approach,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 43(1), 55–79.
Carroll, Christopher D., Martin Sommer, and Jiri Slacalek (2011): “International Evidence on Sticky Consumption Growth,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(4), 1135–1145, http://econ.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/papers/cssIntlStickyC/.
Deaton, Angus S. (1992): Understanding Consumption. Oxford University Press, New York.
Friedman, Milton A. (1957): A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton University Press.
Hall, Robert E. (1978): “Stochastic Implications of the Life-Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Political Economy, 96, 971–87, Available at http://www.stanford.edu/~rehall/Stochastic-JPE-Dec-1978.pdf.
Sommer, Martin (2007): “Habit Formation and Aggregate Consumption Dynamics,” Advances in Macroeconomics, 7(1), Article 21.
This appendix provides additional derivations and notation useful for
simulating the model. One way of interpreting consumers’ behavior in this model
is to attribute to them the beliefs that would rationalize their actions. Define
as the level of wealth (human and nonhuman) that the consumer
perceives. Then the Deaton definition of the permanent income hypothesis is
that
| (15) |
and the reason consumption follows a random walk is that is
precisely the amount that ensures that
.
Writing the “believed” level of wealth as , we could then interpret the
failure of the sticky expectations consumer to change his consumption during the
period of nonupdating as reflecting his optimal forecast that, in the absence of
further information,
.
To pursue this interpretation, it is useful to write the budget constraint more explicitly, as before; start with the constraint in levels, then decompose variables into ratios to permanent income (nonbold variables) and the level of permanent income:
| (16) |
where we permit a time subscript on and
because we want to allow for
the possibility that beliefs about the interest rate or growth rate might change
over time.
Consider an economy that comes into existence in period with a population
of consumers who are identical in every respect, including their beliefs about
current and future values of the economy’s variables.
First we examine the case where neither nor
can change after date
.
In that case, we can track the dynamics of believed and actual variables as
follows.
| (17) |
where capturing the dynamics of the ratio of true permanent income to believed
permanent income requires us to compute
| (18) |
and so
| (19) |
with the crucially useful fact that since by assumption neither nor
is
changing, normalized human wealth does not change from
| (20) |
so that
| (21) |
so that perceived wealth and consumption will be
| (22) |
Matters are more complex if expectations about and
are allowed to
change over time.
Suppose again that we begin our economy in period with population with
homogeneous views: Everyone believes
and
; so long as these
views are universally held in the population, aggregate dynamics are captured by
the foregoing analysis.
Suppose, however, that in some period the economy’s ‘true’ values of
or
change. Updating consumers see this change immediately. But
nonupdaters will not discover the changed nature of the economy’s dynamics
until they update again.
We capture this modification to the model by keeping track of the
aggregate values of the variables for the set of consumers who adhere
to each differing opinion, along with the population mass associated
with the different opinions. Specifically, suppose there are different
opinions in the population, each of whom constitutes population mass
such that
. Then for each such population, it will be
necessary to keep track of their average beliefs about macroeconomic
variables.
Suppose, for example, that through period there have been only
different opinion groups in the population. In period
either
or
changes. We need then to define group
by
and
and to
define
,
, and so on. We will henceforth need to keep
track of dynamics of the consumers who remain in belief group
by,
e.g.,
| (23) |
while we need to keep track of the populations of the differing groups by, e.g.,
| (24) |
and so on. These population dynamics continue forever, but the population of households continuing to hold any specific belief configuration dwindles toward zero as time progresses.
Aggregate variables for the population as a whole can be constructed as the population-weighted sums across all the differing belief groups, weighted by their masses:
| (25) |
and note that if beliefs change back to a configuration that has been seen before it is possible to add the population mass and aggregate values of the variables associated with the new population with that belief configuration to the corresponding figures for the old population that holds the same beliefs. This reduces the number of groups that the simulations must track in the case where beliefs switch between a limited number of distinct values.