© February 7, 2021, Christopher D. Carroll ConsAndLaborSupply

Consumption and Labor Supply

Consider a consumer who has a utility function

u (ct,zt)
(1)

where z
 t  is leisure (mnemonic: z  for laZiness) and c
 t  is consumption. Normalize the maximum possible labor supply to 1  ; actual labor supply is ℓt  , so that

ℓt + zt =  1.
(2)

The wage earned for working one unit of time is Wt  , and labor income is the wage rate multiplied by the amount of labor supplied,

y  =  W  ℓ
  t      t t
   =  (1 −  zt)Wt.
(3)

Suppose the consumer has a fixed amount x
 t  to spend in period t  on consumption and leisure,

x  =  c  + z W   ,
  t    t    t   t
(4)

where xt  can differ from income yt  because this might be a single period in a multi-period problem.

The price of leisure is Wt  (your income is lower by this amount for every extra unit of time you spend not working) and the price of consumption is 1, so the first order condition from the optimal choice of leisure says that the ratio of the marginal utility of leisure to the marginal utility of consumption should be

       (    )
         uz
Wt  =    ---   .
         uc
(5)

To see this formally, note that the consumer’s goal is to

{mcax,z } u (ct,zt).
  t t
(6)

subject to a budget constraint

ct =  xt −  Wtzt
(7)

so (6) becomes

max   u(xt −  Wtzt,  zt)
{zt}
(8)

for which the FOC is

−  ucW   +  uz =  0
       t
           Wt  =  (uz∕uc ).
(9)

This is just the classic condition that says that the ratio of prices of two goods should equal the ratio of their marginal utilities, which applies in any standard microeconomic problem. For a quantitative comparison of how this condition manifests itself in the U.S. and Europe, see Zweibel (2005).

Now, assume there is an ‘outer’ utility function f (∙)  which depends on a Cobb-Douglas aggregate of consumption and leisure

               (  1− ζ ζ)
u (ct,zt) =  f  c t  zt
(10)

The inner function has the property that ztWt  =  ctη  for η =  ζ∕ (1 −  ζ)  , which implies utility can be written

           − ζ
f ((Wt ∕η )  ct).
(11)

        (                    )
                       1− ζ ζ
maxzt  f   (xt − ztWt  )   zt
(12)

FOC:

                         − ζ ζ ′                  1− ζ ζ− 1 ′
(1 −  ζ)Wt (xt −  ztWt  )  zt f  = ζ (xt − ztWt  )   z t  f
                          W   z  = c  ζ∕ (1 − ζ )
                             t t     t◟---◝◜---◞
                                          ≡η
(13)

so

    1− ζ ζ         1− ζ
f (ct   zt ) = f(c t  (ηct∕Wt  )ζ)
                          − ζ
            =  f((Wt  ∕η)   ct)
(14)

Over long periods of time as wages have risen in the U.S., the proportion of time spent working has not changed very much (an old stylized fact recently reconfirmed by Ramey and Francis (2006)). Similarly, across countries with vastly different levels of per capita income, or across people with vastly different levels of wages, the amount of variation in z
 t  is small compared to the size of the difference in wages.

These facts motivate the choice of utility function; King, Plosser, and Rebelo (1988) show that other choices of utility functions produce trends, but no such trends are evident in the data. To see why the trends are produced, think about a model in which the lifetime lasts only a single period, with a lifetime budget constraint W   = c  +  z W
  t     t    t  t  .

We can solve for the level of consumption over the lifetime as

W   =  (1 + η )c
  t             t
 ct =  Wt ∕(1 +  η)
(15)

implying that leisure is

zt =  ηct∕Wt

   =  η∕ (1 + η )
(16)

which is a constant (i.e. the amount of leisure does not trend up or down with the level of wages). Obviously this is what motivates the choice of an ‘inner’ utility function that is Cobb-Douglas: For such a function, people will choose to spend constant proportions of their resources on consumption and leisure as wages rise.

Now consider a two period lifetime version of the model in which each period of life is characterized by a utility function of the same form and the lifetime optimization problem is

max    u (c1,z1 ) + βu (c2, z2)
(17)

subject to a lifetime budget constraint

c2 =  (W1 (1 −  z1) −  c1)R +  (1 −  z2)W2
(18)

From now on, assume that the ‘outer’ utility function is f (χ) =  log χ  . This implies that c2∕c1 =  R β  .

              =-ηc1                   -ηc2
              ◜◞◟ ◝                  ◜ ◞◟ ◝
c2 =  (W1  −  z1W1  − c1)R  + W2  −  W2z2
 0 =  (W   −  (1 + η )c )R  + W   −  (1 +  η)c
         1             1         2             2
c2 =  (RW1  +  W2  )∕(1 +  η) −  Rc1
(19)

so the lifetime optimization problem becomes

maxc1  {log  c1 − ζ log W1  +  β (log c2 −  ζ log W2 )}
(20)

with FOC

1 ∕c  =  R β∕c
    1          2
c2∕c1 =  R β.
(21)

Now we want to compare this to the two period lifetime model with no labor supply decision. In that model, the profile of consumption was unrelated to the profile of labor income over lifetime. (‘Fisherian Separation’ held). In this model, the Fisherian Separation proposition is that the profile of c  is unrelated to profile of wages W  ; however, the lifetime profile of leisure spending is identical to the lifetime profile of consumption spending,

       W2z2 ∕W1z1   =  ηc2 ∕ηc1  = R β

              z2∕z1 =  R βW1  ∕W2
(1 −  ℓ )∕ (1 − ℓ  ) = R βW   ∕W
       2          1          1    2
(22)

so leisure moves in the opposite direction from wages, which means labor supply ℓ =  1 −  z  moves in the same direction as wages. This makes intuitive sense: You want to work harder when work pays better.

To make further progress, assume R β =  1  and define wage growth as G  =  W2  ∕W1  =  (1 +  g)  . Assume that young people tend to work about half of their waking hours ℓ  =  (1∕2 )
 1  (remember vacations, weekends, etc!).

Note that under these assumptions we can rewrite (22) as

(1 −  ℓ )G  =  (1 −  ℓ )
       2              1
          g =  (1 +  g)ℓ2 −  ℓ1

         ℓ2 =  (g +  ℓ1)∕(1 +  g)

            =  (2g +  1)∕2 (1 +  g)
(23)

Empirically, wages in the U.S. tend to grow between youth and middle age by a factor of G  ≈ 2 −  4  (depending on occupation and education), so g ≈  1 −  3  , but labor supply is about the same for 55 year olds as for 25 year olds, ℓ2 ≈  ℓ1   .

Suppose for analysis that g =  2  . Then (23) becomes

ℓ2 =  (5∕6 )
(24)

so the theory says middle aged people work more than young people by (2 ∕6)∕ (3∕6 ) = 2 ∕3  . This is of course absurd - it implies that middle aged people would barely have time to breathe because they were working so hard.

One objection to this analysis is that it assumed Rβ  =  1  , which implies that consumption when young equals consumption when middle aged. In fact, on average consumption grows by about the same amount as wages between youth and middle age. So perhaps the right assumption is R β ∕G  =  1  . Under this assumption, we obviously have ℓ2 = ℓ1   , matching the empirical fact.

However, there is predictably different wage growth across occupations and education groups. Write Gi =  G Γ i  , where Γ i  now will differ for people in different occupations indexed by i  , and plausible values range from Γ  = 0.5  (manual laborers) to Γ =  1.5  (doctors), leaving the average value of Γ  across the two groups at Γ  =  1  . It is an empirical fact that the magnitude of variations in labor supply across these groups is rather small, both in youth and in middle age.

Assuming R β ∕G  =  1  , rewrite (22) for each occupation as

(1 − ℓ  )Γ  =  (1 − ℓ  )
       2  i           1
(25)

For Γ  =  0.5
  i  , if ℓ  =  1∕2
 1  we have

(1 − ℓ2 )0.5 =  1∕2
(26)

implying ℓ  =  0
 2  - manual laborers would work zero hours. However, if Γ  = 1.5  so that

(1 −  ℓ2)(3 ∕2) =  1∕2

     (1 −  ℓ2)3 =  1
             ℓ  =  2∕3
              2
(27)

so doctors would be working much harder when middle aged than when young. Thus, the theory says that if labor supplies are equal when young (which is approximately true), they should differ drastically by middle age (which is not remotely true). That is, lifetime labor supply does not seem to respond very much to predictable variation in lifetime wages. This is described in the literature as a “small intertemporal elasticity of labor supply.”

References

   King, Robert G., Charles I. Plosser, and Sergio T. Rebelo (1988): “Production, Growth, and Business Cycles, I: The Basic Neoclassical Model and II: New Directions,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 21(2/3), 195–232 and309–341.

   Ramey, Valerie A., and Neville Francis (2006): “A Century of Work and Leisure,” NBER Working Paper Number 12264.

   Zweibel, T. Herman (2005): “180 Trillion Leisure Hours Lost To Work Last Year,” The Onion, 41, Available here.