September 21, 2020, Christopher D. Carroll qRamsey
Consider a Ramsey economy in which the capital stock cannot be freely
adjusted; instead, as in the model of investment, capital is subject
to quadratic costs of adjustment. The dynamic budget constraint
is
| (1) |
where for analytical simplicitly we neglect capital depreciation (though the illustrative figures below show results of a model that properly includes depreciation) and the cost-of-adjustment function takes the form
| (2) |
for some constant , so that the cost of adjustment incurred in period
is
given by
| (3) |
A social planner is assumed to maximize the discounted sum of utility from
consumption , where the utility function is CRRA,
.
The social planner’s problem can be rewritten in the form of a Bellman
equation,
|
Because (given ), choosing
is equivalent to choosing
,1
we can rewrite the problem as:
| (4) |
The first order condition is found by setting the derivative w.r.t. to
zero:
| (5) |
The envelope theorem tells us that the marginal value of capital does not depend
on its effect on the investment policy function :
| (6) |
(where notice that does not have the simple interpretation of a share price as
in qModel because here it involves
).
Substituting period ’s version of (6) into (5) allows us to rewrite the
Euler equation in the form:
| (7) |
This economy reduces to a standard Ramsey model when the cost of
adjustment parameter is set to , because all the
terms disappear so
that the interest factor becomes the usual
. The
presence of adjustment costs does not change the steady state of the model
(because in steady state, adjustment costs are zero), but reduces the speed of
convergence toward that steady state. This can be seen by considering the policy
functions plotted in figure 1, where the solid lines reflect the solution to
a model with
(the standard Ramsey model) while the dashed
lines reflect a model with a high cost of adjustment (the ‘
-Ramsey’
model).
The differences between the solid and the dashed loci indicate that a faster
rate of convergence to the steady state requires a high level of below the
steady state at which
and low level of
when
is above
. Higher
adjustment costs work against fast convergence, since, when
is below the
steady state (and positive investment is needed to increase
toward
,
adjustment costs reduce investment, while they increase investment (making it
less negative) when
is above the equilibrium. In both cases, the difference
occurs because because adjusting capital involves convex costs, and thus it
is optimal to proceed slowly in moving the capital stock to minimize
those costs. Interestingly, even though the optimal choices of investment
and consumption change quite substantially in the model with a larger
adjustment cost parameter, the actual size of costs of adjustment borne is
quite modest (the dashing line for
is barely distinguishable from
the horizontal axis except very far from the steady state). This tells
us that even if the observed costs paid are not very large, those costs
can have a large effect in changing behavior away from the frictionless
optimum.
Increasing the desired degree of consumption smoothing, captured by the
coefficient of relative risk aversion , leads to similar implications. Figure 2
shows that a higher
(the dashed loci), implies again lower investment below
the steady state and higher above it. This is now caused by a low intertemporal
elasticity of substitution: if the economy falls below steady state, a larger
implies that the representative agent is less willing to cut consumption in order
to boost investment and quickly return to the steady state. Similarly, the
increase in consumption above the steady state is more moderate, thus
leading to a smaller reduction in investment and a more gradual return to
equilibrium.
By comparing the policy functions, we have thus seen that either an intensified
consumption smoothing motive (higher ) and or a stronger investment
smoothing motive (higher
) have similar implications: they restrain sharp
adjustments to consumption and investment, thus slowing down the speed of
convergence to the steady state.
We now consider the responses of the model to several shocks, starting from
steady state. Figure 3 shows the economy’s dynamics following the destruction of
part of the capital stock. In the standard Ramsey model (black), this
leads to an increase in the marginal productivity of capital which boosts
investment. In the
model with adjustment costs (red), the level of
investment actually falls. This is because costs of adjustment are assumed to be
relative to the size of the capital stock, and with a shrunken capital
stock the original level of investment would incur very large costs of
adjustment. Investment therefore drops to a level that is large relative to
the (shrunken) capital stock but nevertheless smaller than its initial
level. Even this lower investment level, though, is large relative to the
new lower level of the capital stock, and so the capital stock rises back
toward the original equilibrium – just more slowly than in the frictionless
model.
Consumption drops due to the negative wealth effect and the need to finance investment. But since investment is lower initially in the model with investment costs, consumption can be higher initially (the first red consumption dot is above the first black one, post-shock).
(standard Ramsey) in black;
(
-Ramsey) in red
Figure 4 shows the dynamics triggered by an increase in patience,
captured by a permanent rise in . The most striking difference is in the
interest factor
. In the Ramsey model with no investment costs, the
interest rate is simply the marginal product of capital. Here, it must also
take account of costs of adjustment. Since costs of adjustment are high
when the economy is trying to change the size of the capital stock, the
interest rate is lower. This result is interesting because one problem with
using the Ramsey model for studying business cycle dynamics is that
the aggregate capital stock barely moves at all over such a short time
period as a business cycle, so the non-
Ramsey model has no hope of
matching empirical interest rate fluctuations. Adding costs of adjustment
allows much bigger movements in
and thus gives the model a fighting
chance.
Given the lower interest rate (and its implications through the consumption Euler equation), the growth rate of consumption after the increase in patience will be less than in the standard Ramsey model.
Even though consumption drops less, rises more. Recall that
is
a composition of the marginal utility of consumption and the “share
price” of ownership of a unit of capital. The extra rise in
reflects the
fact that the existing capital is more valuable in a period when the rate
of investment will be high (going forward), so the market value of a
unit of “installed” capital rises to above the purchase price of a unit of
capital (which is always 1). This can be interpreted as a boom in asset
prices.