September 21, 2020, Christopher D. Carroll DecentralizingRCK
This handout shows that under certain very special conditions the behavior of an economy composed of distinct individual households will replicate the social planner’s solution to the Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans model.
Consider first the problem of an individual infinitely lived consumer indexed by
who has some predetermined set of expectations for how the aggregate net
interest rate
and wage rate
will evolve.
At date household
owns some capital
, and can in principle also
borrow; designate the net debt of household
in period
as
; since
we will be examining a perfect foresight solution with perfect capital
markets, the interest rate on debt must match the rate of return on assets.
This means that all that really matters is the household’s total net asset
position,
| (1) |
Each household is endowed with one unit of labor, which it supplies
exogenously, earning a wage rate . Each household solves:
| (2) |
subject to the budget constraint
| (3) |
Integrating the household’s dynamic budget constraint and assuming a no-Ponzi-game transversality condition yields the intertemporal budget constraint, which says that the present discounted value of consumption must match the PDV of labor income plus the current stock of net wealth:
| (4) |
The formulas for these PDV’s are a bit awkward because they must take account of the fact that interest rates are varying over time. To make the formulas a bit simpler, define the compound interest factor
| (5) |
which is simply the compound interest term needed to convert a value at date
to its PDV as of time 0.
With this definition in hand we can write the IBC as
| (6) |
where is human wealth,
| (7) |
Each household solves the standard optimization problem taking the future paths of wages and interest rates as given. Thus the Hamiltonian1 is
| (8) |
which implies that the first optimality condition is the usual . The
second optimality condition is
| (9) |
leading eventually to the usual first order condition for consumption:
| (10) |
Note (for future use) that the RHS of this equation does not contain any components that are idiosyncratic: The consumption growth rate will be identical for every household. The same is true of the expression for human wealth, equation (7).
Now we assume that there are many perfectly competitive small firms indexed
by in this economy, each of which has a production function identical to the
aggregate Cobb-Douglas production function. Perfect competition implies that
individual firms take the interest rate
and wage rate
to be exogenous.
Hence firms solve
| (11) |
where and
are the rental rates for a unit of capital and a unit of
labor for one period. Note that, dividing by
, this is equivalent
to
| (12) |
The first order condition for this problem implies that
| (13) |
Under perfect competition firms must make zero profits in equilibrium, which
means, by fact , that:
| (14) |
Thus far, we have solved the consumer’s and the firm’s problems from the standpoint of atomistic individuals. It is now time to consider the behavior of an aggregate economy composed of consumers and firms like these.
We assume that the population of households and firms is distributed along
the unit interval and the population masses sum to one, as per Aggregation.
Thus, aggregate assets at time can be defined as the sum of the assets of all
the individuals in the economy at time
,
| (15) |
while per capita assets are aggregate assets divided by aggregate population,
| (16) |
Similarly, normalizing the population of firms to one yields
| (17) |
Up to this point, we have allowed for the possibility that different households
might have different amounts of net worth. We now impose the assumption that
every household is identical to every other household. This assumption rules out
the presence of any debt in equilibrium (if all households are identical, they
cannot all be in debt - who would they owe the money to?). Indeed, in this case,
the aggregate capital stock per capita will equal the aggregate level of net worth,
.2
Thus, households’ expectations about and
determine their saving
decisions, which in turn determine the aggregate path of
.
There is one important subtlety here, however. In writing the consumer’s
budget constraint, we designated as the net amount of income that would be
generated by owning one more unit of net worth (e.g. capital). But if we have
depreciation of the capital stock, the net return to capital will be equal to the
marginal product minus depreciation. The discussion of the firm’s optimization
problem did not consider depreciation because the firms do not own any
capital; instead, they make a payment
to the households for the
privilege of using the households’ capital. Thus the net increment to a
household’s wealth if the household holds one more unit of capital will
be
|
There is no depreciation of labor, so the labor market equilibrium will be
|
We assume that every household knows the aggregate production function, and
understands the behavior of all the other households and firms in the economy.
Understanding all of this, suppose that households have some set of beliefs about
the future path of the aggregate capital stock per capita . This
belief about
will imply beliefs about wages and interest rates as well
.
The final assumption is that the equilibrium that comes about in this economy is the “perfect foresight equilibrium.” That is, consumers have the sets of beliefs such that, if they have those beliefs and act upon them, the actual outcome turns out to match the beliefs.
Note now that using the fact that in the perfect foresight equilibrium
we can rewrite the household’s budget constraint as
| (18) |
Reproducing from (10),
| (19) |
Now compare these to the equations derived for the social planner’s problem (with population growth and productivity growth zero) in a previous handout:
| (20) |
and
| (21) |
Since the equilibrium value of , (21) = (19). And (18) is identical to
(20). Thus, aggregate behavior of this economy is identical to the behavior of the
social planner’s economy!
This is a very convenient result, because it means that if we are careful about
the exact assumptions we make we can often solve a social planner’s problem
and then assume that the solution also represents the results that would
obtain in a decentralized economy. The social planner’s solution and the
decentralized solution are the same because they are maximizing the
same utility function with respect to the same factor prices ( and
).
When will the decentralized solution not match the social planner’s solution? One important case is when there are externalities in the behavior of individual households; another possible case is where there is idiosyncratic risk but no aggregate risk; basically, whenever the household’s budget constraint or utility function differs in the right ways from the aggregate budget constraint or the social planner’s preferences, there can be a divergence between the two solutions.
Aiyagari, S. Rao (1994): “Uninsured Idiosyncratic Risk and Aggregate Saving,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 659–684.
Carroll, Christopher D. (1992): “The Buffer-Stock Theory of Saving: Some Macroeconomic Evidence,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1992(2), 61–156, http://econ.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/BufferStockBPEA.pdf.
__________ (2000): “Requiem for the Representative Consumer? Aggregate Implications of Microeconomic Consumption Behavior,” American Economic Review, 90(2), 110–115, At http://econ.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/RequiemFull.pdf.
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith (1998): “Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy,” Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), 867–896.