©April 15, 2008, Christopher Carroll HamiltonianVSDiscrete
This handout solves the Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) model using the Hamiltonian method, and shows the relationship between that method and the discrete-time approach.
The problem is to
![]() | (1) |
subject to
In order to emphasize the connection between this continuous-time
problem and the discrete-time problems we have mostly been
working with thus far in class, define the function (k) as the
solution to (1).
The current-value (discounted) Hamiltonian is
![]() | (5) |
where k is the state variable, c is the control variable, and λ is the costate variable.
λ is the continuous-time equivalent of a Lagrange multiplier, so
its value should be equivalent to the value of relaxing the
corresponding constraint by an infinitesimal amount. But the
constraint in question is the capital-accumulation constraint. Thus λ
should be equal to the value of having a tiny bit more capital,
. In other words, you can think of λ =
′(k).
The first necessary condition for optimality is
Note the similarity between (8) and the result we usually obtain by using the Envelope theorem in the discrete-time problem,
The second necessary condition is
which expresses the growth rate of λ at an annual rate (because the interest rate r and time preference rate ϑ are measured at an annual rate).To interpret this in terms of our discrete-time model, begin with the condition
The final necessary condition is just that the accumulation equation for capital is satisfied,
![]() | (13) |
This is the continuous-time equivalent of what we have thus far called the Dynamic Budget Constraint.
Up to now in this course we haven’t thought very much about what the time period is in this model. Generally, we have expressed things in terms of yearly rates, so that for example we might choose R = 1.04 and β = 1∕(1 + ϑ) = 1∕(1.04) to represent an interest rate of 4 percent and a discount rate of 4 percent.
One of the attractive features of the time-consistent model we have been using is that it generates self-similar behavior as the time period is changed. Thus if we wanted to solve a quarterly version of the model we would choose R = 1.01 and β = 1∕1.01 and it would imply consumption of almost exactly 1/4 of the amount implied by the annual model, so that four quarters of such behavior would aggregate to the prediction of the annual model.
To put this in the most general form, suppose R and β correspond to ‘annual rate’ values and we want to divide the year into m periods. Then the appropriate interest rate and discount factor on a per-period basis would be R1∕m and β1∕m. Thus the discrete-time equation could be rewritten
Now, note that since the effective interest rate in this model is
f′(k) - (n + δ), equation (23) is basically the same as (11) since
λ = ′(k) and mΔV ′(kt+1) = (d∕dt)
′(k) =
. Hence, the third
optimality condition in the Hamiltonian optimization method is
basically equivalent to the condition V ′(kt) = RβV ′(kt+1) from the
discrete-time optimization method!
The final required condition (the transversality constraint) is
The translation of this into the discrete-time model is
![]() | (25) |
Consider the simple model with a constant gross interest rate R and CRRA utility. In that model, recall that ct+1 = (Rβ)1∕ρct. Thus considered from time zero (25) becomes
What this says is that you cannot behave in such a way that you expect kt to grow faster than the interest rate forever. Note that this also rules out negative kt values that grow faster than the interest rate.
This is the infinite-horizon version of the intertemporal budget constraint. Among the infinite number of time paths of c and k that will satisfy the first order conditions above, only one will also satisfy this transversality constraint - because all the others imply a violation of the intertemporal budget constraint.
Now differentiate (7) with respect to time