© September 21, 2020, Christopher D. Carroll InvestmentNotes

Investment Notes

1 Broad Comments

1.1 Why Study Investment?

  1. Although investment is much smaller as a fraction of GDP than consumption, investment is much more variable than consumption. So fluctuations in investment spending account for a large proportion of business-cycle frequency fluctuations in GDP. (See the figure below for one way of measuring this).
  2. In the long run, the average magnitude of investment spending determines the size of the capital stock. If we think accounting for capital is an important component of explaining macroeconomic outcomes, then we need an understanding of investment

1.2 History of Thought

2 The Samuelson Multiplier-Accelerator Model

From today’s perspective, the distinctive feature of Samuelson’s model of investment is its emphasis on the proposition that levels of investment were determined by impulses from outside the market for investment. While the model is highly sophisticated in many ways, the essence of it for our purposes can be captured by a very simple equation:

I =  αY   +  γr
 t      t      t
(1)

When paired with equations determining consumption and income, and with some lags added, the model generated the classic Keynesian multiplier-accelerator framework. But the key feature of the investment component of the model was that it assumed that the desired level of investment depended in a simple linear way on the autonomous evolution of other variables: Output Y  and interest rates r  . These variables were in turn affected by I  , and the model was capable of producing rich dynamics as a result. But for the purpose of explaining investment itself, the model’s key implication could be boiled down to (1)

In purely statistical terms, an equation like (1) performs remarkably well in ‘explaining’ investment spending. But this is not very satisfactory because income, investment, and interest rates are presumably all determined by deeper underlying features of the environment, and so it is highly problematic to interpret this equation as instructive about the fundamental determinants of investment.

3 Hall and Jorgensen

Hall and Jorgenson (1967) made an important step forward by constructing a model in which an optimizing firm chooses the level of its capital stock with reference to fundamental features of the economic environment like its production function, depreciation rates, tax considerations, and a comparison of interest rates to the productivity of the firm’s available uses of capital.

HallJorgensen presents a stripped-down version of this model.

An important objection to this framework, however, was that it assumes that firms have the ability to instantly and costlessly move their capital stocks to the level that would be justified by the prevailing economic environment. If something happens to make the firm wish to be larger, it can, say, quadruple its capital stock overnight, paying no cost of adjustment for such a radical change.

4 ϙ  Models

A seminal paper by Tobin (1969) provided the intuition for how to move forward. Tobin defined a variable

      (                            )
         Stock  Mkt  Val  of Firm
Q  =    ---------------------------
        Replacement     Cost  of K
(2)

and proposed that investment should obey the rule

{

  it > 0   if Qt >  1
  i <  0   if Q  <  1
   t            t
(3)

That is, firms which have a value greater than what it would cost to reproduce their capital should be growing, while firms which are not worth what it would cost to reproduce them should be shrinking.

Tobin’s Q  is now one of the basic tools of financial market analysis; it is used regularly as one of several tools designed to try to assess firms’ prospects.

Tobin’s paper inspired a large amount of empirical and theoretical work, culminating in two classic papers, by Abel (1981) and Hayashi (1982), which put the theory on a rigorous mathematical basis. The canonical model that emerged from this literature is summarized in qModel.

5 Imperfect Capital Markets

One of the foundations of the ϙ  model as developed by Abel and Hayashi is its reliance on an assumption that capital markets are perfect, in the sense that in these models investment is pursued right up to the point where the marginal value of an additional unit of investment has been driven down to the exact value of the riskless interest rate (after accounting appropriately for tax features, depreciation, etc), which reflects the optimal quantity of investment.

The key reason that the assumption of perfect capital markets is so useful is that it implies that it is not necessary to keep track of the firm’s cash management or financial activities.

Useful though it may be, the assumption of perfect capital markets is clearly very far from reality. A vast literature has explored what happens when a wide variety of imperfections are introduced. The handout DynanImperfCapMkts.pdf summarizes one particular model of capital market imperfections that produces implications that are similar to those that emerge from many other models.

The implication of capital market imperfections that has been most vigorously explored is that the amount of investment may be affected by a firm’s financial position. The crux of that literature is summarized in iAndCashFlow.

References

   Abel, Andrew B. (1981): “A Dynamic Model of Investment and Capacity Utilization,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 96(3), 379–403.

   Hall, Robert E., and Dale Jorgenson (1967): “Tax Policy and Investment Behavior,” American Economic Review, 57, Available at http://www.stanford.edu/~rehall/Tax-Policy-AER-June-1967.pdf.

   Hayashi, Fumio (1982): “Tobin’s Marginal Q and Average Q: A Neoclassical Interpretation,” Econometrica, 50(1), 213–224, Available at http://ideas.repec.org/p/nwu/cmsems/457.html.

   Samuelson, Paul A. (1939): “Interaction Between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principle of Acceleration,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 21(2), 75–78.

   Tobin, James (1969): “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory,” Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 1(1), 15–29.

Figure 1:Investment Drives the Cycle

pict